Navigating the complexity of negotiations involves balancing contrasting principles: cooperation and competition, both pivotal in their own right. The dynamic tension between these principles can often pose a “negotiator’s dilemma”. Can this equilibrium be managed? Yes, indeed, through an innovative strategy called Multiple Equivalent Simultaneous Offers (MESOs).

Two schools of thought dominate the negotiation arena: the “Value Creators” view negotiation as a harmonious venture aiming for mutual gain through transparent exchange of information and creative problem solving. In stark contrast, the “Value Claimers” approach negotiation as a contest, focusing on outperforming the other party by employing tactics such as highballing, minimal concessions, tight-lipped information sharing, and at times resorting to intimidation.

Though these perspectives might appear conflicting, negotiation experts suggest that an effective negotiator embraces both these perspectives. The trick lies in creating abundant value and assertively claiming a proportionate share. The challenge then emerges when negotiators are not naturally proficient at both.

The negotiator’s dilemma arises when there’s a struggle between the cooperative and competitive aspects of negotiation. This is evident when deciding whether to share sensitive information about interests and priorities. While revealing such information could lead to value creation, it could also leave you vulnerable to exploitation. Conversely, withholding this information could result in missed opportunities or a stalemate.

So how do we overcome this quandary of creating value without exposure to risk and claiming value without straining relationships? This is where the concept of MESOs comes into play.

The initial offer in any negotiation can often trigger destructive competition. Counteroffers tend to lean towards the direction of the first offer, regardless of its fairness or arbitrariness. The counterparty often devalues the first offer, leading to either aggressive counteroffers or abandonment of the negotiation table. To mitigate this, MESOs provide a solution – presenting two or more equally valued package offers for the counterpart to choose from. This strategy communicates goodwill, avoids unnecessary sacrifices, and more often than not, results in a more favorable outcome compared to a single offer scenario.

Let’s take the example of a hiring manager proposing a job offer to a candidate. Instead of presenting a single package or negotiating individual components, the manager could present three equally valued packages, allowing the candidate to choose, thus introducing flexibility and facilitating a mutually beneficial agreement.

However, while making MESOs, it’s crucial to be wary of overwhelming the counterpart with too many options, potentially nullifying the benefits of MESOs.

There are also additional strategies to navigate the negotiator’s dilemma:

  1. Engage a neutral third party like a mediator to facilitate information exchange and reduce potential exploitation.
  2. Develop a single negotiating text, allowing for draft reviews and revisions until a consensus is reached.
  3. Consider a post-settlement settlement, which opens up space for further improvements after the initial agreement, fostering creative thinking and reducing competitive tension.

To conclude, understanding and effectively leveraging MESOs can significantly enhance your negotiation outcomes while managing the inherent dilemmas and balancing the trade-off between competition and cooperation.

The addition of a right of first refusal in your commercial transaction can transform an ordinary deal into a strategic, value-added proposition. To optimize this tool, an astute negotiation of the particulars is non-negotiable.

A ‘right of first refusal’ (RoFR), often referred to as a matching right or right of first offer, is an instrumental clause in business contracts that, if carefully utilized, can bring about significant benefit to both parties. Elucidated by Professor Guhan Subramanian of Harvard Business School and Harvard Law School, an RoFR confers upon one contractual party the privilege to equal any subsequent offer that the other party receives for the item or subject in question.

Consider a property owner negotiating a lease agreement with a potential tenant. The landlord wishes to retain the future option to sell the property, while the tenant seeks to secure a long-term rental agreement. In this scenario, granting the tenant an RoFR – the opportunity to match any genuine third-party offer for the property – serves both parties’ interests. The tenant avoids the inconvenience of relocation, and the landlord retains the flexibility to sell to the highest bidder.

In this context, RoFR emerges as a potentially synergistic instrument, a powerful addition to your negotiation arsenal. However, to actualize its mutual benefits, it is imperative to meticulously delineate the parameters of the agreement.

The Devil is in the Details

Unfortunately, many contracts containing an RoFR clause suffer from ambiguity concerning the process to be followed when a right holder exercises their privilege. Subramanian advises clarity on what ensues when the right holder matches a competing bid. Will this signify the end of the competition, or initiate a bidding war?

Additionally, it’s critical to define the timeframe for deciding to match an offer. An unclear duration can be exploited by a third party through an ‘exploding offer’ – a bid with a tight deadline – potentially preventing a successful match. Ensure you negotiate a generous response period.

Different Flavors of First Refusal

Typically, the holder of an RoFR only needs to match the highest bid without partaking in the auction. However, a variant commonly seen in real estate and entertainment markets requires the right holder to either accept or reject the seller’s price before other potential buyers are approached. If rejected, the right holder forfeits their opportunity to match any future offers.

Researchers Brit Grosskopf and Alvin Roth caution that such a clause could transform an apparent boon into a liability. They posit a situation where you hold an RoFR for a property valued at $500,000. If required to match high bids, you might secure a bargain in a weak market, possibly reacquiring the property for $400,000. However, if you must respond before the market is tested, a demand of $475,000 could compel you to pay near your maximum while risking the loss of the property to a higher bid. Essentially, this scenario pits you against yourself in a bid.

Consequently, ensure that the specific terms of the RoFR will not unexpectedly disadvantage you later.

A Word of Caution for Third Parties

Potential bidders face a conundrum if their offer triggers an RoFR. On one hand, if the right holder exercises their privilege, you may waste time performing due diligence and negotiating. On the other hand, if they do not, you may have overpaid, given that the right holder likely possesses superior knowledge of the asset’s intrinsic value. For this reason, many prefer to eschew deals that invoke an RoFR.

However, certain conditions can alleviate these apprehensions. For instance, the right holder may be unable to match your offer due to liquidity constraints, or you may possess comparable

Our mission at Impact Negotiating is to support individuals and organizations with practical, efficient, and potent negotiating services, enabling them to navigate their personal and professional lives with confidence and ease. We are passionate about helping people unlock their objectives, their potential and we are eager to share our expertise and experiences as an avenue for collaboration, mutual respect, and shared value with you through this blog.

Read more